HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/toolbar/bp_logo.gif” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/about/” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/contact2.htm” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/search.htm” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/research/” http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ PRIVATE “TYPE=PICT;ALT=Customized Benchmarking Studies” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/tab1.gif” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/research/” http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ HYPERLINK “http://www.benchmarkingreports.com” PRIVATE “TYPE=PICT;ALT=Detailed Benchmarking Research Reports” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/toolbar/tab2.gif” HYPERLINK “http://www.benchmarkingreports.com” HYPERLINK “http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com” http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ PRIVATE “TYPE=PICT;ALT=Immediate Access to Best Practices Research” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/toolbar/tab3.gif” HYPERLINK “http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com” http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/” http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ PRIVATE “TYPE=PICT;ALT=Fast Response Benchmarking in Customer Service, Knowledge Management and Sales” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/toolbar/tab4.gif” HYPERLINK “http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/” http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ HYPERLINK “http://www.globalbenchmarking.com” PRIVATE “TYPE=PICT;ALT=Fast Access to World-Class Companies” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/toolbar/tab5.gif” HYPERLINK “http://www.globalbenchmarking.com” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/toolbar.gif” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/corner_ul.gif” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/corner_ur.gif” Michael Porter On How To Marry Strategy & Operational Effectiveness The Harvard management guru argues that operations & strategy must “fit” to create a sustainable competitive advantage. For almost two decades, managers have been learning to play by a new set of rules. Companies must be flexible to respond rapidly to competitive and market changes. They must benchmark continuously to achieve best practice. They must outsource aggressively to gain efficiencies. . . Positioning — once the heart of strategy — is rejected as too static for today’s dynamic markets and changing technologies. According to the new dogma, rivals can quickly copy any market position, and competitive advantage is, at best, temporary. . . But those beliefs are dangerous half-truths, and they are leading more and more companies down the path of mutually destructive competition. Distinguishing Between Operational Effectiveness and Strategy INCLUDEPICTURE d “images/porter_quote1.gif” Operational effectiveness and strategy are both essential to superior performance, which is the primary goal of any enterprise. But they work in very different ways. . . Operational effectiveness (OE) means performing similar activities better than rivals perform them. Operational effectiveness includes but is not limited to efficiency. It refers to any number of practices that allow a company to better utilize its inputs by, for example, reducing defects in products or developing better products faster. In contrast, strategic positioning means performing different activities from rivals or performing similar activities in different ways. . . Constant improvement in operational effectiveness is necessary to achieve superior profitability. However, it is not usually sufficient. Few companies have competed successfully on the basis of operational effectiveness over an extended period, and staying ahead of rivals gets harder every day. Strategy is the creation of a unique and valuable position, involving a different set of activities. If there were only one ideal position, there would be no need for strategy. Companies would face a simple imperative — win the race to discover and preempt it. The essence of strategic positioning is to choose activities that are different from rivals’. If the same set of activities were best to produce all varieties, meet all needs, and access all customers, companies could easily shift among them and operational effectiveness would determine performance. Developing Strategic Fit Across Activities Strategic positions emerge from distinct sources, which often overlap. First, positioning can be based on producing a subset of an industry’s products or services. I call this variety-based positioning. . . A second basis for positioning is that of serving the needs of a particular customer group. I call this needs-based positioning. . . The third basis for positioning is that of segmenting customers who are accessible in different ways. I call this access-based positioning. . . Positioning choices determine not only which activities a company will perform and how it will configure individual activities but also how activities relate to one another. While operational effectiveness is about achieving excellence in individual activities, strategy is about combining activities. The importance of fit among functional policies is one of the oldest ideas in strategy. Gradually, however, it has been supplanted on the management agenda. Rather than seeing the company as a whole, managers have turned to “core” competencies, “critical” resources, and “key” success factors. In fact, fit is a far more central component of competitive advantage than most realize. Strategic fit among many activities is fundamental not only to competitive advantage but also to the sustainability of that advantage. It is harder for a rival to match an array of interlocked activities than it is merely to imitate a particular sales-force approach, match a process technology, or replicate a set of product features. Positions built on activity systems are more sustainable than those built on individual activities. INCLUDEPICTURE d “images/porter_quote2.gif” Finally, fit among a company’s activities creates pressures and incentives to improve operational effectiveness, which makes imitation even harder. Fit means that poor performance in one activity will degrade the performance in others, so that weaknesses are exposed and more prone to get attention. Conversely, improvements in one activity will pay dividends in others. Companies with strong fit among their activities are rarely inviting targets. Their superiority in strategy and in execution only compounds their advantages and raises the hurdle for imitators. Strategy is creating fit among a company’s activities. The success of a strategy depends on doing many things well — not just a few — and integrating among them. If there is no fit among activities, there is no distinctive strategy and little sustainability. Management reverts to the simpler task of overseeing independent functions, and operational effectiveness determines a company’s relative performance. Improving operational effectiveness is a necessary part of management, but it is not strategy. In confusing the two, managers have unintentionally backed into a way of thinking about competition that is driving many industries toward competitive convergence, which is in no one’s best interest and is not inevitable. Both Strategy and Operational Effectiveness Are Critical to Success Managers must clearly distinguish operational effectiveness from strategy. Both are essential, but the two agendas are different. The operational agenda involves continual improvement everywhere there are no trade-offs. Failure to do this creates vulnerability even for companies with a good strategy. The operational agenda is the proper place for constant change, flexibility, and relentless efforts to achieve best practice. In contrast, the strategic agenda is the right place for defining a unique position, making clear trade-offs, & tightening fit. It involves the continual search for ways to reinforce & extend the company’s position. Strategic continuity does not imply a static view of competition. A company must continually improve its operational effectiveness and actively try to shift the productivity frontier; at the same time, there needs to be ongoing effort to extend its uniqueness while strengthening the fit among its activities. Strategic continuity makes an organization’s improvements more effective. This report is excerpted from “What Is Strategy?” by Michael E. Porter, Harvard Business Review, Volume 74, Number 6, pp 61 – 78. HYPERLINK “../../site_tools/contact2.htm” Sign up to recieve a Monthly Best Practice Spotlight HYPERLINK “http://www.benchmarkingreports.com” Find this Spotlight in a Full Report- The Marketplace of Best Practices, LLC INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/corner_ll.gif” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/corner_lr.gif” INCLUDEPICTURE d “../../images/research/tag_line.gif” HYPERLINK “../../site_tools/contact2.htm” ????????????倫 http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/contact2.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/contact2.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/search.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/search.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ Valued Gateway Client”C:My DocumentsMichael Porter.doc?䀁老 {1A31A0A0-5705-11D4-BC29-00E09876CEFC} {1A31A0A0-5705-11D4-BC29-00E09876CEFC} http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.best-in-class.com/forums/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.bestpracticedatabase.com/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/research/ http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/search.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/search.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/contact2.htm http://www.best-in-class.com/site_tools/contact2.htm The Competitive Advantage of Nations and Regions Michael E. Porter continues to extend his study first reported in The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Porter has published books and studies of other countries, states, and cities, including Canada, New Zealand, Portugal, the Commonwealth of Massachusetts, and India. A book on Japan (with visiting professor Hirotaka Takeuchi), tentatively titled The Two Japans, is expected to be completed in 1999. Porter is extending his microeconomics-based theory of competitiveness in a variety of ways. He is exploring the shifting role of various microeconomic influences as a nation’s economy becomes more advanced, and the relationship between macroeconomic conditions and microeconomic conditions in development. Porter’s examination of the problems of early-stage economic development includes research with Pankaj Ghemawat on India, as well as studies on Central American, South American, and Asian countries. Porter is also conducting statistical research on the microeconomic foundations of economic development. An initial paper “The Microeconomic Foundations of Economic Development” (in The Global Competitiveness Report 1998, Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum, 1998) examines the role of microeconomic variables in explaining per capita income differences among 52 countries. A paper with Mariko Sakakibara (UCLA) examines the link between domestic rivalry and international competitive success in a sample of Japanese industries. Porter is also conducting research into appropriate forms of economic cooperation within regions (including countries), for which a major project involving the presidents of seven Central American nations is serving as a laboratory. Porter is conducting ongoing research on the theory of clusters, or geographic concentrations of interconnected companies and institutions in a particular field. This work includes further development of cluster theory and its implications for management and public policy (see On Competition, Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1998 and “Clusters and the New Economics of Competition,” Harvard Business Review, November-December 1998).
The Term Paper on Swisher Mower Company Advantages Of Alternative
SWISHER MOWING AND MACHINE COMPANY EVALUATING A PRIVATE BRAND OPPORTUNITY TABLE OF CONTENTS TABLE OF CONTENTS 2 Background Statement 3 Major Issue / Problem 3 Alternative One 3 Advantages of Alternative One 4 Disadvantages of Alternative One 5 Quantitative Implications 5 Alternative Two 5 Advantages of Alternative Two 5 Disadvantages of Alternative Two 6 Quantitative Implications 6 Alternative ...
The Essay on Competitive Advantage
Competitive Advantage It is perhaps not surprising that in an era when the resources for health promotion are limited and the expectations as to what can be achieved are high, that sustainability has become a familiar catch-cry. Yet all too often enthusiasm has overshadowed critical reflection on whether aiming for sustainability is warranted, let alone feasible. There has been a lack of consensus ...
The Essay on Telecommunications Technology Can Provide A Firm With A Competitive Advantage
Describe in detail the ways that telecommunications technology can provide a firm with a competitive advantage. A competitive advantage can be achieved by enhancing the firms ability to deal with customers, suppliers, substitute products and services, and new entrance into its market. A firm may find it difficult to keep informed of all changes taking place within its industry, but with the proper ...
The Research paper on Does Your Company Have A Competitive Advantage
Does Your Company have a Competitive Advantage? Krispy Kreme Doughnuts, Inc. was created in 1937 by Vernon Rudolph. Nowadays Krispy Kreme Doughnuts, Inc. is a popular chain of doughnut stores that offers quality coffee roasting at significant discounts because of direct buying channels and unique know-how recipes, new improved coffee and new Hot Doughnut Machine technologies. According to MSN ...
The Research paper on Learning New Research Concepts or Techniques by Writing and Other Research Activities
The way to go about determining if certain resources are adequate for college assignments would be through an evaluation process. In chapter five of the course material, it provides the six tests of evidence that helps to conclude if discovered information can be utilized for a paper. The first test is regarding credibility. If a source is credible it should be information based on fact rather ...
The Business plan on Financial Management Tools And Competitive Advantage
Introduction The long-term survival of a firm seems to be dependent more on the firm’s competitiveness. No matter how much physical, human and intellectual resources, an organization is able to mobilize, its long-term survival will be in jeopardy if it fails to stay competitive. The firm therefore needs to be able to determine its level of competitive advantage vis-a-vis that of its ...
Porter is also conducting statistical research on the incidence, growth, and decline of clusters in the U.S. economy. With Claas van der Linde of St. Gallen University in Switzerland, he is also conducting a meta-study of clusters drawn from almost 350 known studies of individual clusters. National Innovative Capacity and the Ideas Production Function Joint research with Scott Stern (MIT) is exploring the determinants of innovative capacity across countries using time series/cross-section data (“Measuring the “Ideas” Production Function: Evidence from International Patent Output,” draft working paper, July 1998).
Using international patenting as a weighting variable, Porter and Stern have devised an index of national innovation capacity. The data has also been employed to directly estimate critical parameters of the ideas production function, a central element in economic growth theory. Sustainable Inner-City Economic Development Michael E. Porter is using the framework he developed in The Competitive Advantage of Nations to examine the economic development problems in distressed inner-city areas. He seeks to understand the potential of inner-city businesses, government policies, and private-sector initiatives to contribute to sustainable economic development. Porter’s project has yielded a series of articles (see “The Competitive Advantage of the Inner City,” Harvard Business Review, May-June 1995) and led to the development of a private-sector organization called the Initiative for a Competitive Inner City, which is catalyzing inner-city development efforts across the nation. Environmental Policy and Competitiveness Michael E. Porter has been exploring (with Claas van der Linde of St. Gallen University, Switzerland) the relationship between environmental regulation, industry competition, and international competitiveness. He finds that many forms of environmental pollution reflect inefficient resource utilization and poorly developed technology, suggesting that better environmental performance is often consistent with enhanced competitiveness. This perspective recasts the role of governmental regulation, highlighting the importance of regulatory and corporate approaches that foster innovation and improve resource productivity rather than simply abate or prevent pollution Capital Markets, Investment, and Competition Michael E. Porter’s research into issues of capital allocation, first published in the report “Capital Choices,” is the basis for continuing research that examines how U.S. capital markets distort competitive behavior and investment. A report to the Competitiveness Policy Council, “Lifting All Boats,” contains recent research and policy recommendations. Porter is engaged in a major new body of work on the theoretical foundations of competitive positioning and the underpinnings of sustainable competitive advantage. This research highlights the distinction between positioning and operational effectiveness; the fundamental role of differences in company activities in positioning; and the central importance of tradeoffs in delivering different types of customer benefit to the sustainability of differences in positioning; the role of fit among a firm’s activities (or activity systems); competitive advantage and sustainability; and the relationship between strategy, organizations, and incentives. He is exploring his ideas in theoretical papers, mathematical models, and company studies. An early discussion of this body of work appears in “What is Strategy?”, Harvard Business Review, November-December 1996 and Activity Systems as Barriers to Imitation,” Harvard Business School Working Paper #98-066. Porter’s next book on strategy, focusing on these ideas, is nearing completion. Michael Porter and Anita McGahan are completing a series of statistical papers on the sources of company and industry profitability. Based on large new database on the profitability of U.S. business segments between 1981 and 1994, their research examines topics such as the relative importance of industry; business segment positioning; corporate parent effects on superior or lagging profitability; the persistence of profit differences over time; and how high and low performers differ along such dimensions. | E-mail: [email protected] | Biography | Publications | | Competition & Strategy Unit | HBS Directory | Last updated Wednesday, November 4, 1998 For the full interview with Harvard Business School Professor Michael Porter, see the Oct. 1, 1995, issue of “CIO.” Competitive advantage is one of the three golden aspirations of any ambitious CIO. Along with adding value and setting strategic agendas, creating competitive advantage remains a pipe dream for many a CIO. That’s because information systems departments are too often pigeonholed into an internally focused operational support mode. But it doesn’t have to be that way, says one of the most influential modern theorists in competitive strategy. Michael E. Porter, the Roland E. Christensen professor of business administration at the Harvard Business School, wrote the landmark 1980 work, “Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors.” In that book, and in later works, Porter reconciled historical views on competitiveness and defined the concepts of unique positioning. Porter’s more recent research has been a reaction to what he sees as the last decade’s worrisome infatuation with operational improvement efforts — something he contends does little to sustain competitive advantage. In effect, Porter tells “CIO” Managing Editor Richard Pastore, IS and the businesses it serves are both missing the strategic mark. What concerns you most about the way companies today are looking at competitiveness? As companies emerge from the last decade, many have been preoccupied with operational effectiveness — restructuring, reengineering and improving efficiencies. These improvements are a necessity in today’s competition, but they alone are not enough. They are approaching a point of diminishing returns. If companies are going to sustain competitive advantage, they can’t do it by being more efficient at running the business. They have to have a distinctive way of competing. The necessity of carving out a distinctive competitive position is not understood as well as it needs to be today. In a lot of companies, there is a mistaken sense that there is only one right strategy for that industry, and if one company can be the first to discover and implement it, they’ll win. We’ve found from our research over the years that this way of thinking is ultimately self-destructive. If everybody’s racing to discover one right strategy, nobody wins. What’s behind your new theory of complementary activity systems? Rarely does sustainable advantage grow out of a single activity in a business. A company doesn’t get sustainable advantage simply because it has some unique product design or a unique sales force. Those kind of advantages tend to be visible targets to imitate. If it relies on one activity as its key strength, all its competitors are going to work very hard to match that–especially if it is dubbed a best practice against which everybody else is benchmarking. Sustainable advantage comes from systems of activities that are complementary. These “complementarities” occur when performing one activity and gives a company not only an advantage in that activity, but it also provides benefits in other activities. For example, if a company has a very good inventory management system, it can also offer faster delivery and do so cheaper than a company without the inventory management system. Companies with sustainable competitive advantage integrate lots of activities within the business: their marketing, service, designs, customer support. All those things are consistent, interconnected and mutually reinforcing. As a result, competitors don’t have to match just one thing, they have to match the whole system. And until rivals achieve the whole system, they don’t get very many of the benefits. It’s like climbing a cliff; until you get to the top of the cliff, you can’t stand and begin to walk again. Where does IT fit into these concepts? Can it promote the creation of these complementarities? Yes. In many cases, achieving complimentarities across activities is heavily affected by information technology. A production process can benefit a company’s after-sales service if there is effective information exchange. If IS people need a new rallying cry for how to create competitive advantage, maybe it ought to be around the idea of tying activities together and achieving complementarities. What can chief information officers specifically contribute toward competitive positioning? CIOs understand the enabling technologies to allow distinctive positions to be created, so the CIO has an important role to play. But that doesn’t mean that systems should be built internally, and it doesn’t mean that the CIO should control all the systems activity in the company. There will continue to be a need for integration and certain standards and protocols, but that’s getting easier because the software itself is pushing it. The idea of central IS as traffic cop and enforcer is less important, and the CIO’s role should increasingly turn to supporting competitive advantage. http://www.cio.com/CIO/cio_buttons.maphttp://www.cio.com/CIO/cio_buttons.map http://www.cio.com/CIO/http://www.cio.com/CIO/ Teaching Note 7: The Competitive Environment and Competitive Advantage 1.There are two fundamental issues, according to Michael Porter. First, is the industry/market attractive? – i.e. capable of delivering a healthy profit stream. Second, how might advantage be obtained and sustained? 2.Porter argues that five forces determine the profitability of an industry. The threat of new entrants; barriers to entry The bargaining power of suppliers The bargaining power of customers The threat of substitute products/services At the heart of the industry are rivals and their competitive strategies linked to, say, pricing or advertising; but, Porter contends, it is important to look beyond one’s immediate competitors as there are other determinants of profitability. Specifically there might be competition from substitute products or services. These alternatives may be perceived as substitutes by buyers even though they are part of a different industry. An example would be plastic bottles, cans and glass bottles for packaging soft drinks. There may also be a potential threat of new entrants, although some competitors will see this as an opportunity to strengthen their position in the market by ensuring, as far as they can, customer loyalty. Finally, it is important to appreciate that companies purchase from suppliers and sell to buyers. If these forces are powerful they are in a position to bargain profits away through reduced margins, by forcing either cost increases or price decreases. This relates to vertical integration. Any company must seek to understand the nature of its competitive environment if it is to be successful in achieving its objectives and in establishing appropriate strategies. If a company fully understands the nature of the five forces, and particularly appreciates which one is the most important, it will be in a stronger position to defend itself against any threats, and to influence the forces with its strategy. The situation, of course, is fluid, and the nature and relative power of the forces will change. Consequently, the need to monitor and stay aware is continuous. Competitive advantage implies a distinct, and ideally sustainable, edge overcompetitors. It is more than the idea of a competitive strategy, which may or may not prove distinctive. Porter has also shown how companies can seek broad advantage within an industry or focus on one or a number of distinct segments. He argues that advantage can accrue from: i.cost leadership, whereby a company prices around the average for the market (with a “middle-of-the-road” products or service) and enjoys superior profits because its costs are lower than those of its rivals; ii.differentiation, where value is added in areas of real significance for customers, who are then willing to pay a premium price for the distinctiveness. A range of differentiated products (or services), each designed to appeal to a different segment, is possible, as is focus on just on a segment. There are, consequently, four generic strategies: cost leadership, differentiation, cost focus, differentiation focus. An organization (according to Porter) should concentrate on just one of these and not be “stuck” in the middle”. Speed (say, quicker new product development) and fast reaction to opportunities and threats can provide advantage, essentially by reducing costs and differentiating. Real competitive advantage implies companies are able to satisfy customer needs more effectively than their competitors. Because few individual sources of advantage are sustainable in the long-run, the most successful companies innovate and seek continually new forms of advantage in order to open up a competitive gap and then maintain their lead. Achieving this successfully is a cultural issue, as we have seen. Competitive advantage, then, does not come from simply being different. It is achieved if and when real value is added for customers. This often requires companies to stretch their resources to achieve higher returns. Improved productivity may be involved; ideally, employees will come up with innovations, new and better ways of doing things for customers. Porter has provided another framework for examining the sources of added value. He argues there are five primary activities and four support activities – listed below. Each of these is a cost and, therefore, a potential source of cost leadership; each activity can also be the source of any differentiation. The linkages between the activities are particularly important. thompnote7.htm – topthompnote7.htm – top by Stan Sorscher, SPEEA Executive Board Rational end-game strategy Leading by example The Role of Employees Change in a Theory X Culture A well-designed business strategy is designed to make money for the owners, by competing in markets and selling products at a profit. In some cases, however, business leaders may decide that their market is no longer attractive or a product line is no longer profitable. At that point, it is appropriate to ?harvest? the business1 and extract as much value from the enterprise as possible. Exit strategies can be very lucrative, if managed properly. By merely imitating your competitors, you cannot prevail. You must offer your customers an advantage that differentiates your products from competitors?. Michael E. Porter wrote, ?The fundamental basis of above average performance in the long run is ?sustainable competitive advantage? … Without a sustainable competitive advantage, above-average performance is usually a sign of harvesting.? (see footnote) Business writers talk about three types of advantage. You might be the low-cost producer, attracting customers by underselling competitors. Alternatively, you might offer features or options which attract customers through value. Finally, you might operate in a market segment that gives you an advantage. Typically, the low cost producer is also a high-volume producer, offering standard products, commanding a large share of the market. While providing the lowest price, you must maintain approximately the same quality as your competitors. Customers might find value from features, customized designs, operating advantages, immediate availability, service or maintenance experience, high reliability, training, or good resale value. Non-economic considerations, such as brand loyalty, ?image?, or even nationalism may be significant elements of product differentiation. The customer must be willing to pay extra for the features that differentiate your product. Furthermore, you must be able to produce the higher-value product for less than the sales price. Specializing in a small portion of a large market or operating across related markets can create structural advantages over competitors who are trying to serve other customers. Commercial Airplane Strategy for Boeing Consider the low-cost strategy. We heard recently that our products were mature – ?approaching theoretical perfection.? Additional differentiation was not justified. We waged a fierce campaign for market-share based on cost. The results were not satisfying. Many customers claimed that competing products approached theoretical perfection more closely than ours. Our business strategy remains weighted toward ?cost.? In DCAC language, a low-cost strategy encourages Tailored Business Stream 1 features, and discourages TBS 2 and TBS 3. We might consider a strategy weighted toward product differentiation. How would we use our resources? In a product differentiation strategy, we would encourage TBS 2 and 3, relying on the options in DCAC to provide value to customers. Furthermore, we would need highly-effective financial systems, so that we could price options properly. Another key resource would be awareness of our customers? needs and preferences, and an accurate means of computing the value our options would have in our customer?s business operations. We claim all these elements as key initiatives or core competencies. Looking at a market-segment strategy, I can imagine focussing on business jets, airplane modification, airport ground operations, air traffic control, or some other market segments, looking for competitive advantages through interactions among business units. Interactions between commercial, military, space, and communications operations are traditional examples of this. I am not really familiar with Lean Manufacturing, or platform teams, but I believe they could serve a range of business strategies. Two weak links, from my point of view, are our highly sub-optimized Theory X management culture and our glaringly backward employee relations practices. Our Theory X culture is at its best in standard, well-established stable operations. It is particularly ill-suited to changing environments and evolving conditions. Both the product differentiation strategy and the market segment strategy would require excellent communication, committed employees who understand their role in the business, and a general ability to respond quickly to changing markets and customer requirements. We are at a distinct competitive disadvantage in those areas. The first major decision, of course, is whether to compete or harvest. Our share of the commercial airplane sales could easily drop from leader to follower this year. US Steel concluded that its steel markets were fundamentally unattractive. Their shareholders made a great deal of money harvesting their steel business, then shifting to other market segments. Other examples come to mind readily. If we intend to compete, then we should compete! For the first time in many months, I am starting to see a return of interest in product development and process improvement. I hope we continue to regain our focus on customers, products, and processes. As employees, we are ready to build on our strengths and work toward a common goal: building long-term value for shareholders, customers and employees. Competitive Advantage, Michael E. Porter, 1985, p. 11. /summer/contributed-papers.htmlBack to contributed papers page /summer/summer-info.htmlBack to summer institute home page Competitiveness, Sustainability, and the North American System of Innovation Background paper for the Trinational Summer Institute, Whistler, British Columbia, 14-21 Aug. 1994 International Development Research Centre International Development Research Centre Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean In Canada as well as in other countries, many of the concerns about the appropriateness of the technological basis of economic production are being expressed in terms of problems of competitiveness, sustainability, and innovation. Science and technology policies and innovation management practices, in particular, are addressing the competitiveness and sustainability agendas from an innovation perspective.1 Specialists have spilt much ink debating the meanings and implications of the notions of competitiveness and sustainability. Each notion often works as a metalanguage with its own set of assumptions, problems, and agenda of prescribed actions. The competitiveness and sustainability agendas share a sometimes apocalyptic language to describe the consequences of failure to attain competitiveness or sustainability. Both are frequently held up as imperatives which challenge systems of innovation at the deepest levels. The competitiveness and sustainability agendas do not frequently refer to each other, and in many respects they talk past or contradict each other. There are few overlaps or linkages between the sustainability and competitiveness’ policy networks and interest groups. However, the two agendas are each increasingly sensitive to problems of technological innovation, and each hints at the necessity or the inevitability of a new “techno-economic paradigm” upon which the next century’s peace and prosperity can be based. In one formulation that is strongly advocated by some technology policy advisory agencies, a strategic course of technological innovation provides the only way to reconcile the two conflicting goals of reducing levels of pollution and resource deterioration while achieving major, sustainable increases in economic activity. In other words, a particular course of action regarding technological innovation may provide an intersection between the competitiveness and sustainability agendas. This paper is meant to stimulate discussion about a social science research agenda on innovation, sustainability, and competitiveness in the North American region. I will try to be explicit about the paper’s assumptions. First, I use the term “competitiveness” to refer to the ability to successfully offer products or services in an open trading system, in exchange for income, despite others who offer similar products or services, thus maintaining or expanding access to the life chances that income can purchase. Competitiveness is a frequently cited rationale and objective of innovation policy measures in Canada. I use the term “sustainability” to refer to development that does not pass on undue or irreversible environmental costs to succeeding generations.2 The term “innovation” usually refers to the first commercial application of a product or process by a user.1 This definition of innovation is close to what is commonly understood as “technological progress” and it focuses attention on increases in efficiency and productivity. About one-third of U.S. economic growth between 1929 and 1982 can be attributed to innovation of this sort (Denison, 1985).
A broader definition of innovation to address issues raised by the competitiveness and sustainability agendas is required because the larger the increment of technological change, the more likely organizational or social innovations are involved. Understanding innovation at the managerial, organizational, social, or cultural levels requires, at the very least, that a host of conceptual and measurement problems be addressed. Second, I claim that two of the most consistent (and increasingly explicit) policy agendas of our times, the competitiveness and sustainability agendas, are committed to stimulating, guiding, or directing science and technology to achieve their ends. Each agenda attempts to influence technological and industrial innovation in the narrow sense and each ponders the broader issues of institutional and social innovation, raising a host of questions about ends and means. Third, innovation takes place in “systems” of public and private institutions and the rules and routines of their behavior. Innovation research uses notions such as “system of innovation” (Niosi et al. 1993; Nelson 1993) to describe the social institutions of innovation. The set of distinctions among minor and major forms of technological change employed by evolutionary economists helps to address the level-of-analysis problem that one encounters when searching for the boundaries of a system. Freeman (1992) distinguishes among innovation at the level of the firm, the production system, the technology system, and the technoeconomic paradigm. These distinctions identify progressively larger increments of change in current practices of production, and progressively broader groups of organizations and behaviors taken as reference points. Incremental innovations are minor cumulative changes continuously occurring in firms which can add up over time to significant improvements in productivity and efficiency. Radical innovations are discontinuities in the production system. Nylon and the oxygen steelmaking process are historical examples. More recently, radical innovations “are usually the result of deliberate research and development in enterprises and/or in university and government laboratories” (Freeman 1992).
Changes of “technology system” are the result of clusters of radical innovations that create “far- reaching changes in technology, affecting several branches of the economy, as well as ultimately giving rise to entirely new sectors.” Synthetic materials and the associated manufacturing techniques are examples. Technological revolutions, or change of “technoeconomic paradigm,” are “new technology systems which have such pervasive effects on the economy as a whole that they change the style of production and management throughout the economy” (Freeman 1992).
Technological innovation entails organizational, social, or cultural innovation. Fourth, I inquire whether it might be useful to develop and apply a “systems of innovation” approach in the North American region. The existence of a North American system of innovation may be surmised on the basis of the considerable degree of economic integration that has taken place among the United States, Mexico, and Canada. However, the contours and dynamics of this system have not been well described. Fifth, my discussion focuses primarily on problems of industrial innovation, and the section on sustainability is correspondingly limited. Issues of natural resource management, energy, transportation, sustainable cities, or sustainable agriculture need to be examined from an innovation perspective, but it has not been possible to do it here. While neither competitiveness nor sustainability (however defined) is imaginable in the absence of innovation, the key issue, in my view, is the degree to which a production system can be both competitive and sustainable in a given context. As North American economic integration proceeds, science and technology policies and private management strategies will respond to the emerging conditions of innovation in the region. Subregional patterns of economic activity will change, and successful social mastery of new configurations of production will be an important skill to acquire. The greening of technology policies and management practices presents a new set of challenges in the context of trade regional liberalization, heightened intra- and inter-regional competition, and increased mobility in factors of production. 2. A North American System of Innovation The notion of “system of innovation” can be operationalized in terms of financial flows, legal and policy links, and flows of information, science, technology, and people (Niosi et al. 1993).
Among the legal and policy measures that are contributing to an integrated North American innovation system are the NAFTA rules governing investment, intellectual property, and technical standards. Among the financial and technology flows is the huge volume of bilateral trade between the United States and its two neighbors, especially intrafirm trade. Among the flows of science are the innumerable linkages between Canada and the U.S. on the one hand and the U.S. and Mexico on the other. The familiar “hub-and- spokes” pattern of North American economic interchange, in which the United States’ neighbors entertain extensive interactions with it but very little with each other, is paralleled in patterns of scientific communication.1 A regional system integrator is an actor that aligns and integrates the economic and technological systems of regional members in interaction with them, including bilateral and multilateral trade, direct investment, official development assistance, non market technological collaboration (for example, military), political relationships, provision of services, establishment of trade rules, export of production technology, and export of the “software” of technological development such as management beliefs, social science paradigms, administrative and technical curricula, information, publications, symbolic reward systems, etc. (Yama*censored*a 1991).
These linkages help spread a pattern of growth into related economies. In Asia, the Japanese role of regional integrator may represent “an enlargement of the parent-subcontract industrial relation” to include newly industrializing countries (Yama*censored*a 1991, 4).
In Europe the role of systems integrator is played by a supranational institution, the European Community, its multitude of programs and policies, and the networks of firms and institutions within the regional economic space. The United States, its large firms, and the regional trade rules are the principal innovation system integrators in North America. In contrast to trends in Asia and Europe, science, technology, and innovation have not been prominent considerations in the discussions about the North American region’s future. Before the present decade, neither Canada, nor the United States, nor Mexico tended to see itself as a member of a North American “community” or “system.” Most attention focused instead on the extensive bilateral relationships between Canada and the United States on the one hand, and between Mexico and the U.S. on the other. It was implausible to suggest that North America might evolve into a region possessing a specific, shared identity and continental-scale institutions. Regional economic integration is reshaping the North American economic landscape. The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) establishes a framework for a trade regime encompassing one of the largest (about 360 million people) and richest (about $6 trillion) regional markets in the world. NAFTA sets trade rules for a regional economy that has already undergone substantial integration. Canada and the United States have the world’s largest bilateral trade relationship, and the United States is Mexico’s largest trading partner. NAFTA includes provisions for the reduction and eventual elimination of most tariffs affecting commerce among Canada, the United States, and Mexico in commodities, manufactured goods, and services. However, NAFTA goes beyond tariff elimination to establish rules governing trade and investment. The three countries agree not to discriminate against each others’ goods and services, and to eliminate most tariffs over a decade. Customs procedures and temporary entry for business travellers are simplified. Mexican import licensing procedures are immediately eliminated. The chapter on rules of origin sets out formulae by which Mexican, American, or Canadian products incorporating third-party materials or components can qualify for preferential access to each other’s markets. Under the net cost formula, most products qualify for preferential treatment with 50% North American content. In the case of light vehicles, the figure is 62.5%. This provision is designed to discourage new transplants from using Mexico to supply the U.S. automotive market. The rules for determining North American content can be complex in practice, and their primary implication for manufacturing is in sourcing practices. NAFTA extends national treatment to member countries’ suppliers of goods and services to public markets. NAFTA signatories agree not to impose offsets or performance requirements in public procurement. Improved tendering and dispute resolution procedures are specified. The rules governing public procurement are broader than those in the GATT procurement code, and NAFTA, in its extension of procurement rules to subnational governments (states, provinces, and municipalities), goes well beyond the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement. The net result is to liberalize a North American public market of about $70 billion. NAFTA sets rules regarding control over foreign investments. It establishes the principle of national treatment for all three parties regarding investments, establishment of new businesses, acquisition and sale of businesses, and the conduct and operation of businesses. No minimum levels of equity may be imposed on purchases or ownership. No performance requirements (for import substitution, local sourcing, export targets, foreign exchange generation, production sharing, product mandates, hiring of nationals in management positions, or technology transfer) may be imposed on investments from any of the three countries or on any investments from any third country (Article 1106).
However, governments may offer “advantages” to firms in exchange for commitments regarding R&D, training, expansion, or location of production facilities. Canada retains the investment screening regime established under CUFTA (the right to review direct acquisition of Canadian controlled firms valued at more than C$ 150 million).
No restrictions may be placed on the patriation of profits and transfer payments. Mexico retains a range of investment prohibition privileges in the energy and communication sectors. Unlike CUFTA, NAFTA contains a chapter setting out rules for intellectual property. Chapter 17 applies standards regarding sound recordings, literary and artistic works, software, data, designs, copyright, trademarks, and patents. It makes provisions for enforcing intellectual property rights, and it restrains the parties’ latitude to permit compulsory licensing of patents. NAFTA also contains provisions governing energy, natural resources, agriculture, financial services, technical standards, telecommunications, cultural industries, and transportation services. Like the Agreement’s provisions discussed above, the general thrust is to deregulate and liberalize trade in these industries within North America, and to specify special cases in which governments retain rights to discriminate. Two “side agreements” cover labor and environmental issues. However, the disciplines envisaged by these two agreements in case of noncompliance are weak (Shrybman, 1993; Martin 1992).
Continental market liberalization necessarily modifies the options available to policymakers to structure national or subnational economic development, and reduces the range of policy instruments available. Because NAFTA establishes new rules of the game for regional trade, it has been called an “economic constitution for North America.” What are the implications of NAFTA for innovation policy and management? In the first place, NAFTA clearly restrains governments from imposing performance requirements on foreign investors, North American or other, and considerably reduces governments’ latitude to screen foreign direct investment (FDI).1 Also, under NAFTA governments cannot impose performance requirements but may negotiate some kinds of innovation-related performances with firms in exchange for incentives. In the second place, like CUFTA, NAFTA contains no rules governing subsidies, one of the most difficult issues on the trade policy agenda. Many kinds of government assistance have been labelled subsidies in U.S.-Canada trade disputes, including grants, tax credits, low-interest loans, and unemployment insurance. The subsidy issue was not resolvable during CUFTA negotiations. In the case of NAFTA, the subsidy issue was referred to the GATT, where the recently signed Dunkel text contains rules governing publicly- supported R&D and other kinds of subsidies. Since NAFTA does not cover subsidies, the “rules of the game” are unclear regarding direct or indirect public involvement in initiatives that help create advantage in the private sector. Given the uncertainty about subsidies, policymakers in Canada and Mexico will probably pay close attention to innovation policy practices in the United States in the belief that American practices will set a de facto standard in the region. The Clinton administration has adopted a more vigorous approach to promotion of industrial innovation than the two preceding administrations. In the third place, NAFTA is clearly intended to cover the activities of subnational governments, insofar as the respective Federal governments are empowered to commit subnational governments through international agreements. This will have the same effects on state and provincial innovation policies as on national policies in North America. Many states and provinces have developed quite extensive programs and institutions in support of innovation. Similarly, many American cities offer substantial industrial incentives. Tax and subsidy competition among localities is widespread in North America. European and North American regional trade arrangements shield regional economies from offshore competition. However, the two regional arrangements are based on quite divergent philosophies. Europe has adopted a “Keynesian” approach to regional economic integration, creating a wide range of institutional arrangements to address economic and social issues. European economic integration involves “an attempt to build an administrative framework that takes into account the economic efficiency and collective security needs of the community, by means of the creation of a genuinely mixed economy at the regional level, when it seemed no longer viable on a national level” (Deblock and Rioux 1993: 32).
In contrast, NAFTA, like the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement it superseded, largely concentrates on removing barriers to the movement of goods and capital. NAFTA is a “negative” approach to regional economic integration. It is concerned largely with removing tariff and nontariff barriers to movements of goods, services, and capital. It has no mechanisms to promote positive adjustment to economic integration. Problems of adjustment are largely left to the national governments to resolve. A regional trade agreement provides preferences among member countries, and fosters intraregional trade at the expense of interregional trade. Continental trade liberalization is precipitating wide discussion in North America about jobs, the environment, and national sovereignty. What are the implications of economic continentalization for science and technology strategies in the region, considering the increasingly integrated continental production system into which the two smaller countries have opted, and considering also the constraints placed by NAFTA on use of a wide range of traditional instruments of industrial and economic policy? The rationale for trade liberalization is well known. Manufacturing firms require economies of scale to compete in global markets, and production efficiencies are determined by relative size of market. Under tariff protection, inefficient, subcritical plants produce short runs of excessively diverse product lines. Access to a large market and increased competition should lead to rationalization and accelerated R&D investments (Daly and MacCharles 1986).
Trade liberalization should induce manufacturers in Canada to rationalize within the North American market, decreasing unit costs and reducing the productivity gap with the United States (ECC, 1988).
One expects increased competition to improve the technical and allocative efficiency of firms (Globerman 1990).
Thus economic gains from trade liberalization are principally realizable in the presence of productivity growth via attainment of economies of scale, increased internal R&D investments, and a higher rate of technological diffusion within firms and their supplier networks. As for the reorganization of production in North America, the simplest assumption is that of segmented production, with resource extraction, mass assembly operations, and higher R&D and management functions all sited in different locations. However, a much wider range of organizational responses is available to firms, such as just-in-time production (and its implications for proximity to suppliers), strategic alliances, multilocational production strategies, flexible specialization and the like (Eden 1991; 1994).
Concern is being voiced that the North American trade regime provides strong incentives for manufacturers “to respond to market competition with a low-wage strategy, which will lower incomes and productivity over the long run, rather than [take] the more difficult path of producing quality products more efficiently.”1 This would create downward pressures on social and environmental standards in North America. While the objective pursued by conventional trade policy is to increase the “allocative” or “Ricardian” efficiency of the economy, the rationale of development-oriented innovation policy is to increase the “growth” or “Schumpeterian” efficiency of the economy (Dosi, Zysman, and Tyson 1990, 25).
A major task facing policymakers, practitioners, and innovation scholars in North America is to identify plausible routes to technological learning in open economies and assemble a collection of policy instruments that are relatively effective (i.e. likely to induce technological spillovers into the economy), efficient (i.e. do not entail disproportionately high costs), and acceptable under the prevailing trade regime. 3. Industrial Innovation and Canadian Competitiveness Canada is a trading nation. Approximately 30% Canada’s GDP is generated through international trade, and the combination of imports and exports amounts to half of Canada’s GDP. Of the G-7 countries, only in Germany does international trade contribute a higher proportion of GDP. Although much of the discussion about innovation in Canada has been pitched in terms of adjustment to “globalization,” Canada’s international trade is mainly continental. About three-quarters of Canadian trade is with the United States, and more than half of this is intra-firm trade. Furthermore, Canadian international trade is highly concentrated. About 70% takes place via about 50 firms, half of which are of Canadian origin. The search for competitiveness has created an eager market for indicators, yardsticks, and report cards in Canada. These provide sometimes paradoxical views on the state of Canadian competitiveness. According to the United Nations Human Development Index in 1992, Canadians enjoy the highest quality of life in the world. According to the OECD, Canada recently had the fastest increase in employment among the G-7 countries and the second highest growth rate. But the World Competitiveness Report’s 1993 survey ranked Canada eleventh among twenty-two industrialized countries, down from fourth place just four years earlier. The World Competitiveness Report gave relatively high marks to Canada’s financial system (3d place) and infrastructure (5th place), but low marks to Canadian science and technology strategies (16th place), quality of production technologies (15th place), trade diversification (20th place), quality of management (14th place), and investment in new equipment (21st place).
Of all countries surveyed, only Britain’s manufacturing base had deteriorated more dramatically than Canada’s. Canada has lost an estimated half million manufacturing jobs since 1989, with manufacturing’s share of overall employment falling to about 15%. The unemployment rate is about 11%, and by mid-1990s the net public debt/GDP ratio will have climbed to about 75% – up from about 30% at the beginning of the 1980s. Canada is carrying one of the highest per capita public debts among advanced countries. Canadian competitiveness has been dissected and debated in an avalanche of reports and studies.1 Many believe that Canada’s overall technological effort is too modest, and R&D expenditures too heavily dependent on the public sector, to help realize Canada’s aspirations to maintain an advanced economy. To get to the bottom of the competitiveness question, in 1990 the Federal government and the Business Council on National Issues commissioned Harvard Business School strategist Michael Porter to apply his renowned “diamond” analysis to Canada. In The Competitive Advantage of Nations (1990) Porter says that a nation’s goal is to improve the standard of living by increasing the growth of industry through increasing industrial productivity and through shifting resources to higher productivity segments. This will normally happen as industry works to reduce unit costs and differentiate products, but industry will not choose to do so unless faced with competition (rivalry) and opportunities for innovation in their markets. Nations are “competitive” if their firms can engineer not just cost improvements but also differentiation. International rivalry normally pushes firms down product streams toward highly differentiated products. This requires constant innovation on the part of the firm. Internationally competitive firms create a virtuous cycle in which reinvestment drives further growth through innovation and learning. Mass production strategies are abandoned to less-developed countries. The most appropriate national innovation strategy is one that encourages firms to compete at the high end of the market through innovation, product differentiation, and service delivery, in contrast to sole reliance on traditional cost-cutting, productivity-enhancing measures.2 Porter’s thesis is that national competitive advantage is embedded in a “competitive diamond” of four essential attributes. These are: Factor conditions (labor, land, natural resources, infrastructure, labor skills, and services to industry); Demand conditions (the quality and strength of home-market demand for local industrial output. Porter attaches considerable importance to the presence of knowledgeable, demanding local customers); Related and supporting industries, especially the presence or absence of internationally competitive suppliers; and Firm strategy, structure and rivalry, which constitute the conditions in which companies are created, organized, and managed. Porter says that firms have a “home base” where the key strategic decisions are taken and where the core product and process technologies are maintained. He says that if firms do not use their national “home base” in this way, they do not contribute to competitiveness of the national economy. Porter’s Canadian report, ominously entitled Canada at the Crossroads, argues that Canada is not doing so well in the new competitive environment (Porter, 1991).
Five trends indicate underlying weaknesses: low productivity growth, high unit labor costs, persistently high unemployment, lagging investment in skills and technology upgrading, and an unencouraging macroeconomic climate for productive investments. Porter observes that Canada is deficient in vigorous export industries. Most Canadian exports are in natural resources industries (materials and metals, forest products, and petroleum and chemicals), with some other successful exporters in transportation (mainly automobiles and avionics) and food and beverage industries (Porter, 1991).
In other words, Canada is specialized in exports of unprocessed or semi-processed commodities. Many of the sales of the relatively higher value-added exporters, such as chemicals or autoparts, go to a very small number of parent firms in the United States. Porter concludes that in Canada, natural resource factor advantages are more important than innovation-related “created advantages,” and that an abundance of natural resource-related factors does not necessarily lead to new factor creation, it leads to specialized resource firms. One might expect an indigenous capital goods industry to service the resource industries, but this has not happened in Canada. Furthermore, Canadian domestic demand plays a minor role in the development of internationally competitive Canadian firms; the American market and American suppliers predominate. Domestic rivalry is usually not significant in internationally competitive Canadian industries, nor do these industries develop local clusters of upstream and downstream linkages. Canadian regional development policies prevent geographical concentration of firms, and foreign direct investment in Canada has reduced the importance of supporting industries through intrafirm transactions or vertical integration. Moreover, Porter notes that few non-North American firms have developed a “home base” type relationship with Canada. Porter irked defenders of continental economic integration when he suggested that high levels of foreign direct investment in Canada are an impediment to international competitiveness. Canada has one of the highest levels of foreign ownership of industrial assets of any advanced country, raising the question of “the extent to which foreign ownership inhibits the development of a national innovation system and, indeed, whether a national innovation system is necessarily preferred to integration into an international system” (McFetridge 1993: 320).
Porter’s analysis provoked a debate about the appropriateness for small countries of the “national diamond” competitiveness framework. Canada’s home country diamond “does not have the answers to explain Canada’s international competitiveness,” say D’Cruz and Rugman (1992), who are concerned with the strategic behavior of MNCs operating from small, open economies. To be applicable to Canada, the Porter model needs to be corrected “for the nature of foreign direct investment in Canada, the value added in Canada’s resource industries, and the relevance of Canada’s home country diamond in an integrated North American economic system” (ibid.).
In a stream of publications, Rugman and D’Cruz have put forward a series of critiques of the Porter model in particular and of the more generally held belief in Canada that policies to promote indigenous manufacturing or high technology firms firms are critically important. D’Cruz’s and Rugman’s analysis of Canadian competitive advantage is based on the recognition that most Canadian firms are concentrated in sectors or production phases in which cost reduction is the primary competitive strategy. Canada’s ten leading export industries are automobiles, pulp and paper, vehicle components, commercial vehicles, non-edible agricultural products, non-ferrous metals, crude oil, cereal products, natural gas, and motors, turbines, and pumps. With the exception of the automotive sector, Canadian export performance “is not determined by an ability on the part of its manufacturing sector to compete in international markets. It depends instead upon the output of the natural resource sectors” (D’Cruz and Rugman 1992: 21).
Also, Rugman and D’Cruz take issue with Porter’s selection of strategic industrial clusters. In Fast Forward: Improving Canada’s International Competitiveness (1991), they identify ten subregional clusters accounting for the bulk of Canadian GDP and note that seven of the ten clusters are in the resource sector or in wage-sensitive production phases of manufacturing.1 They view competitiveness in these industries as largely determined by productivity growth, which in turn is driven by factor costs, especially wage and capital costs. In other words, indigenous advanced-technology development is not regarded as important in these sectors’ competitiveness. The problem of staples-driven economic development is the central theme of Canadian economic history. Trade in primary products is a very slowly growing segment of world trade. This is partly because barriers to entry are relatively low, encouraging exports from the Third World and soon from the former Soviet Union. Of equal concern is the phenomenon of “dematerialization” of production, in which information-rich, highly engineered components such as optical fibers, ceramics, or high- strength composites replace simple commodity-based components.2 Because of competition and dematerialization of production, the long-term trend for commodity prices is down. In 1992 the Economist “reported that real commodity prices were at their lowest level since the magazine began calculating an all-item index in 1845” (Pestieau 1993: 2).
Canada has specialized its international trade in a small range of slow-growth commodities concentrated in the North American market. Canadian resource firms typically develop firm-specific process innovations which provide advantage. They maintain technical currency through procurement of foreign machinery, licenses, patents, and foreign producers, and when they do undertake R&D it is frequently abroad. Thanks to their cultural or geographic proximity to American and British technology markets, Canadian multinationals “are probably among the fast ‘technology followers'” (Niosi 1983, 189).
However, compared to their competitors in other countries, Canadian firms distinguish themselves by choosing to compete more on the basis of cost than on the basis of innovation. For example, a recent study of innovation strategies in the Canadian non-ferrous metals sector found that R&D spending had declined in the 1980s, remaining at less than one percent of sales, while R&D spending in comparable Japanese and European firms had doubled to more than two percent of sales (SCC 1992b).
This behavior reflects deliberate strategy, not just costs of production. According to Japanese and Finnish managers of mining companies quoted in the study, conventional business operations generating half or more of total revenues received only a small fraction of the R&D budget, while research on higher value-added activities – new materials and new products – received up to ninety percent of the R&D budget.3 A second key shortcoming of the Porter model when applied to small, open economies, according to Rugman and D’Cruz (1993), is that one cannot measure the international competitiveness of smaller countries in terms of export shares because “much of the business of smaller countries is conducted abroad (through foreign direct investment) within the larger triad markets of the United States, E.C. and Japan – where the action is.” Porter does not count overseas sales by the subsidiaries of Canadian-owned multinationals in export share data, giving the impression of poor Canadian export performance. Dunning (1993) points out that there are three kinds of cross-border commercial interactions: arm’s length trade, inter-firm cooperative agreements, and foreign direct investment. He argues that Porter has substantially underestimated the importance of globalized production, especially the cross-border value added activities of transnational firms, much of which takes place as intrafirm trade. Canada is an important exporter of capital. Canadians invest abroad almost as much per capita as Americans. Between 1987 and 1991 about $5.4 billion was invested in the country annually, while about $6.6 billion was invested outside the country annually. In 1990 the foreign direct investment stock in Canada stood at $125.3 billion and the Canadian direct investment stock abroad stood at $86.7 billion (U.N. 1993).
In 1990 Canada had some 1300 indigenous MNCs. Even the resource industries are footloose. Between 1980 and 1990, incoming foreign direct investment stock in the primary sector in Canada increased only slightly from $4.6 billion to $5 billion, while Canadian outward direct investments in the primary sector increased from $2.7 billion to $5.7 billion. The largest increases in outward FDI in the past decade are not in the primary sector however, but in low value-added segments of the secondary sector and in parts of the tertiary sector. In the former, the Canadian outward FDI stock increased from $17.3 to $46 billion between 1980 and 1990, with huge increases in FDI stock in food and beverages ($2.3 to $5.8 billion), paper ($2 to $10.5 billion), coal and petroleum products ($.9 to $6.5 billion), metals ($5.5 to $14.2 billion), and other manufacturing ($.9 to $3 billion).
Canadian outward FDI in the tertiary sector increased from $7 to $34.9 billion, with the largest increase in the financial and insurance industries ($3.7 billion to $24.7 billion between 1980 and 1990).
In 1990 Canada had $86.7 billion of FDI outside the country, of which 61% was in the U.S., 21% in Western Europe, and 13% in developing areas (United Nations 1993).
Porter’s model raises questions about how two-way FDI contributes to a “small” country’s competitive advantage. This is a critical issue for “small” countries. In the past, incoming FDI has been considered much more significant than outward FDI in discussions of Canadian economic competitiveness. This is especially true in the context of understanding the accumulation of technological capability. A long debate within Canada has considered the pros and cons of incoming FDI and, in particular, its effects on domestic innovatory capability. Porter believes that outward FDI is valuable in creating competitive advantage, but that foreign subsidies are not sources of competitive advantage and that inward FDI is “not entirely healthy” (as cited in D’Cruz and Rugman 1993).
The opportunity to centralize operations and rationalize production in a regional market is especially attractive to manufacturing MNCs in mature or price-sensitive industries which “are among the leading proponents of the strategy to narrow product mix and expand production runs” (Litvak 1990, 118).
However, a closer look at the often conflicting set of pressures toward globalization and localization shows that the strategic consequences of these pressures are not identical across industries. Some firms develop multinational or global, highly rationalized structures, and others develop transnational structures or purely local structures (Crookell 1990; Eden 1991).
Multinational firms respond to changes in terms of ownership advantages, internalization advantages, and locational advantages; new information-based manufacturing technologies and trade policy changes also influence locational decisions (Eden 1991).
Because of these factors and the importance of the U.S. market, the Canadian “diamond” is not necessarily of primary significance to Canadian firms. They also must take into account the U.S. “diamond” and for this reason small trade-dependent countries like Canada, Denmark, and New Zealand must look at their competitive advantages in terms of the domestic “diamonds” of their principal markets. This requires a “double diamond” strategy (Rugman and D’Cruz 1993).
I have described at some length one of the debates on Canadian competitiveness to illustrate some of the ways that transnationalized production within the continental economy complicates the analysis of competitiveness. Integration into a larger system of innovation raises questions of how to make the best of proximity to this larger system. Although alarms about global environmental degradation have been sounded for the past three decades, the environmental situation today is different in four new ways (Rath and Herbert-Copley 1993: 7): * rapid increase in the scale of pollution has accelerated loss of soil, species, clean water, and natural environments. * tens of thousands of synthetic chemicals, most of which are untested as to toxic or environmental effects, are replacing natural pollutants. * the transboundary impacts of environmentally disturbing human activities require international or transnational remedies that can be long and complex to put in place. * because “the various environmental threats are inextricably linked, both in their causes and effects,” they cannot be addressed or solved in isolation one from the others. There is growing acceptance of the “precautionary principle” and the clean production paradigm in environmental management. The precautionary principle, which was endorsed by the Earth Summit at Rio de Janeiro in 1992, discourages attempts to establish environmental management strategies based on calculation of the pollution carrying capacity of the environment, with innovation aimed at waste management and production of end-of-pipe pollution abatement techniques. Instead, the precautionary principle advocates reduction to zero of all emissions of substances that are “persistent, toxic and liable to bioaccumulate…even where there is no scientific evidence to prove a causal link between emissions and actions” (Jackson 1991: 8).
The clean production paradigm advocates approaches such as product lifecycle assessment and closed-cyle industrial ecological design to foster across-the-board prevention of pollution in industrial systems (Dethlefsen, Jackson, and Taylor, 1993; Hirschhorn, Jackson, and Baas, 1993).
The principles of “clean production” are precaution (i.e. reduction of anthropogenic inputs into the environment), prevention (i.e. extend the analysis of environmental implications of production as far upstream as possible), and integration of environmental protection measures across system boundaries (i.e. integration of protection measures into the production process) (Jackson 1993b).
The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency defines pollution prevention as “source reduction” that eliminates or reduces pollutants through improvements in equipment, technology, processes or procedures, redesign or reformulation of products, substitution of raw materials, and “improvements in housekeeping, maintenance, training and inventory control.” Recycling, re-use, and end-of-pipe pollution control are excluded. The Technology Innovation and Economics Committee of the U.S. National Advisory Council for Environmental Policy and Technology advocates a hierarchy of technological approaches to environmental improvement: “in order of desirability, these are: technologies that prevent pollution (including waste minimization and source reduction technologies), recycling technologies, environmental control [i.e. end- of-pipe] technologies, and cleanup [i.e. remedial] technologies” (EPA 1991).
Distinctions between minor and major forms of technological innovation suggest ways of distinguishing between tactical and strategic approaches to technological change. Tactical interventions aim to accelerate the incremental improvement of the environmental efficiency of existing industry by reducing wastage and increasing recycling. They would put in place policy and economic incentives and disincentives, management paradigms, and investment and training strategies to produce many small improvements on a broad front. Strategic interventions would aim to innovate substantially improved technologies, radically improved technological systems, or new technoeconomic paradigms. The distinction between innovation of minor and major magnitude is being taken up by national and international policy and program agencies. For example, the OECD advocates a three-pronged transition to the “fourth industrial revolution,” the clean industrial production revolution comparable to the steam, steel- electricity, and electronics revolutions. * The first thrust is to induce incremental improvements in industrial performance by acting to identify, deploy and implement existing cleaner technologies through provision of information, removal of barriers to trade and implementation, government purchasing programs, and so on. * The second thrust is to accelerate technical and technological change by acting to promote innovative development and widespread implementation of new generations of cleaner technologies, through enunciation of coherent goals and policies such as Japan’s New Earth 21 Plan or the Netherlands’ National Environment Policy Plan Plus, which sets long term environmental quality goals; * The third thrust is to sustain environmentally sound industrial innovation by acting to ensure that cleaner technologies become and remain the basis for economic development in the long term through education and collective action, innovation of cleaner technologies, etc. (OECD 1993, ix-x).
The conjunction of innovation policy and environmental policy is relatively recent. Environmental sustainability has not been a major consideration among mainstream innovation policy and management researchers. Winn and Roome (1993) recently searched the core R&D management literature of the past two decades for work on environmental issues, and identified only nine articles. Clarke and Reavely’s (1993) 10,000-item bibliography of core science and technology management literature contains references to only 31 documents that focus explicitly on environmental issues. Similarly, the literature on “green” innovation policies is relatively small and dispersed among the literatures on environmental management, environmental economics, risk assessment, and economics of innovation. As in any policy area, one wishes to know what the policy objectives are and what they should be, which instruments are deployed and why, and what are their effects, including costs and benefits; one also wishes to understand the policymaking process. Key environmental policy instruments for industry are regulations, technical assistance to firms, economic instruments such as tax and liability arrangements, consensus-building processes such as roundtables, and international agreements.1 A comprehensive pollution prevention environmental policy regime should include 1) technical assistance programs; 2) education and training; 3) financial incentives; 4) increased use of liability regulations; and 5) “regulations specifically requiring the development of waste reduction plans and the submission to governments of regular reports on their progress in waste reduction” (Baas et al. 1992: 14; Yakowitz and Hanmer, 1993).
Regulation is the most widespread mechanism of public control of industrial environmental performance. Most research on the effects of environmental, health, and safety regulation is designed to determine its effects on productivity and profitability. In a review of this research, the Office of Technology Assessment (1994) concludes that environmental regulation was responsible for 10 to 15 percent of the productivity slowdown in the U.S. in the 1970s, but that “other factors (such as technology changes, investment, and training) were more important” (p. 325).
Of growing interest is research on the effects of environmental regulation and standards on the rate and direction of innovation for the improvement of the design of regulations and standards. Promotion of acquisition of environmentally improved industrial technology is becoming an important environmental policy goal. The structure of incentives and disincentives to invest in minor or major forms of industrial innovation having some relation with environmental sustainability is clearly of central importance. The design of environmental policy from an innovation policy perspective must ensure that counterproductive policy measures from other domains, such as subsidies for energy, water, or local raw materials, are detected and dealt with.2 The traditional approach to control of industrial pollution is through implementation of end-of-pipe (EOP) technologies, the main effect of which is to displace the pollution charge from one medium to another. Concomitant with this approach to environmental industrial technology policy are regulatory regimes based on concepts of environmental assimilative capacity or critical pollution loads.3 Historically, “technology diffusion has played a limited and subordinate role to regulation, permitting, and compliance in the regulation-based environmental management system” (EPA 1992: 15).
This is because the regulation-based environmental policy systems of the 1970s encouraged investments in pollution control technologies rather than in environmental improvement of processes, products, housekeeping, and materials handling. Permitting and compliance regulatory frameworks created a demand for add-on pollution abatement techniques, a demand reflected in national S&T policies. In the former West Germany, for example, governmental support for R&D on clean technologies focussed largely on invention of end-of- pipe pollution abatement techniques (Bongaerts and Heinrichs 1987).
Once investments have been made in end-of-pipe pollution control technologies, there is little incentive to adopt the more comprehensive pollution prevention management paradigm. Furthermore, suppliers of pollution control solutions may resist movement toward a precautionary policy regime: “experience in the U.S. has shown this to be a significant issue, because the end-of- pipe approach has advocates and a large industry selling the hardware of pollution control (e.g. scrubbers, incinerators, waste treatment plants)” (Hirschhorn 1992: 11).
Regulations “must be explicitly designed with technological considerations in mind – that is, they should be fashioned to elicit the type of technological response desired” (Ashford 1993: 296).
The regulatory design “should combine an assessment of the innovative capacity of the possible responding industrial sectors with levels and forms of regulation tailored to that capacity. The entire process should reflect a realistic evaluation of the best possible achievable technological goal” (ibid. p. 289).
The EPA’s National Advisory Council for Environmental Policy and Technology emphasizes that disincentives to technological innovation and adoption environmentally improved technologies must be removed from regulatory permitting and enforcement (EPA 1992, 1991).
Technical assistance to firms for improvement of environmental performance is another public policy instrument which has led to recent institutional innovation in Canada and the United States. Technical assistance institutions can be classified on a four-point scale of increasing involvement in a firm’s decision-making (Doyle 1992).
At level one, the technical assistance institution provides information and networking services. There are many public and private environmental technology databases and referral services available, including ICPIC, the International Cleaner Production Information Clearinghouse. At Level Two, in addition to providing information the technical assistance institution brokers specialized services such as business planning, market assessment, and identification of financial sources. Many Chambers of Commerce and Business Innovation Centers operate at this level. At Level Three, the technical assistance institution provides technical and financial infrastructure support, including (for example) operation of incubators, prototyping services, technical services, and arm’s- length financial assistance. This is a hands-on technical assistance role that requires proactive behavior on the part of the institution. An example of a Level Three institution in the United States is NETAC, the National Environmental Technology Applications Corporation. NETAC provides business evaluations, technology evaluations, regulatory and intellectual property assistance, training, and technical services such as testing and demonstration. It also has a product evaluation center specialized in bioremediation technologies. At Level Four, the institution participates directly in the firm through equity investments and close technical and management ties. An example is the Finnish National Fund for Research and Development (SITRA), an independent public fund of about US$ 100M with the mission to take research to market. It supports new ventures through minority equity participation (Doyle 1992).
Overall, “an important lesson from the United States is that cleaner production outreach programmes can take many different forms. There is considerable variation in the pollution prevention programmes managed by the 50 states. The programmes are located in a variety of institutions and provide a diverse array of services” (UNIDO/UNEP 1992: 7).
Deliberate transition to cleaner production at the firm level can begin with a waste audit, the “first step in an on-going programme designed to achieve maximum resource optimisation and improved process performance. It is a common sense approach to problem identification and problem solving” (UNEP/UNIDO 1991b).
The waste auditing procedure advocated by the United Nations agencies: * defines sources, quantities and types of wastes being generated; * collates information on unit operations, raw materials, products, water usage and wastes; * highlights process inefficiencies and areas of poor management; * helps set targets for waste reduction; * permits the development of cost-effective waste management strategies; * raises awareness in the workforce regarding the benefits of waste reduction; * increases management’s knowledge of these processes; * helps to improve process efficiency (UNEP/UNIDO 1991b: 3-4).
The result of a waste audit is the development and implementation of an action plan to reduce waste and improve production efficiency which, if implemented, can provide significant economic benefits to the firm, as indicated by the findings of the Dutch PRISMA program, one of the programmatic models for UNEP/UNIDO cleaner production programs. The PRISMA waste auditing procedure identified about 200 hundred pollution prevention options among a group of corporate participants. Only 30% of these options implied technological modifications; 30% implied improvement in housekeeping procedures, 30% implied changes in materials and raw materials, and 10% implied product modifications (Huisingh and Baas 1991: 28; see also Dieleman and de Hoo, 1993).
Taken together, housekeeping procedures, material inputs, production technologies, and product parameters constitute “industrial practice.” Significant benefits can be gained from incremental improvements in existing industrial practice, especially in relatively backward subregions of North America where the stock of equipment and the skill sets of workers and management are all likely to be farther from good practice than in technologically dynamic subregions. The precautionary principal and the clean production paradigm hint that they can move toward major changes of technology systems through many incremental improvements in production and transformation of management philosophy. Also of interest is the development of new R&D-based production systems in which ecoefficiency is a critical design parameter. The capacity to create technologies has never been greater in industrialized countries. The world is currently on the brink of a new technoeconomic paradigm based upon information and image technologies, biotechnology, new materials, and a range of improved energy technologies. The technical characteristics of radically different technologies for long term environmental sustainability are still largely speculative, and the environmental implications of various configurations of the emerging technoeconomic paradigm are only beginning to be explored (OECD 1991; Freeman 1992).
It is not so simple to identify kinds of “clean” or environmentally sound technologies the promotion and diffusion of which are to be encouraged. Since no currently known technologies are perfectly clean or entirely environmentally sound, cleanliness or environmental soundness are relative. The key characteristic of cleaner technologies is that they are cleaner than prior technologies with respect to materials flow, energy efficiency, or toxicity. Cleaner technologies: * extract and utilize natural resources and prepare products as efficiently as possible; * use as little energy and raw materials as possible per unit of product output and per unit of utilization (useful lifetime) of the product; * generate products with reduced or no potentially harmful components; * minimize releases to air, water, and soil during fabrication and use of product; * ensure that any residua of production and use which are generated are managed in an environmentally sound manner; * ensure, for non-perishable goods, that product durability and lifetimes are maximized insofar as practicable; and, after the useful function is ended, products or their key components are recoverable insofar as possible (OECD 1993: 2).
These characteristics can apply to many techniques and practices across the entire range of industries. As a World Resources Institute report observes, “today the climate for innovation seems uniquely rich, poised between technological revolutions in progress and others just emerging” (Heaton, Repetto, and Sobin 1991: 7).
A huge reservoir of untapped technological potential in biotechnology, materials, and informatics exists which could increase energy efficiency and reduce waste production. A World Resources Institute report proposes environmentally critical technologies for the United States1 and proposes environmental technology policy initiatives which include a federal Institute for Environmental Technology, new funding arrangements to support environmental technological innovation, new missions for national laboratories, new patterns of R&D cooperation, new arrangements for international cooperation, regulatory reform, and reorientation of existing programs (Heaton, Repetto, and Sobin, 1992).
Most industrialized countries have taken measures to stimulate innovation of new generations of environmentally sound technologies. The Japanese are probably the most ambitious in this respect. Their “New Earth 21” plan aims develop a new industrial paradigm to restore the Earth’s natural functions over the next century by returning the emission of global warming gases to pre-industrial revolution levels. They have established RITE, the Research Institute of Innovative Technology for the Earth, for development and global promotion of next generation environmental technologies. RITE is applying advanced technologies to problems of renewable energy, energy efficiency, new manufacturing processes, and capture and fixation of carbon dioxide. Germany, the Netherlands, Italy, and Canada are other industrialized countries which have established national initiatives to support development of strategic environmental technologies. A number of recent authors incorporate the precautionary principal into frameworks for action. Simonis (1989), for example, identifies three strategic elements of environmental modernization of industrial society: ecological structural economic change (notably actions to delink growth from environmentally relevant input factors); preventive environmental policy; and ecological orientation of environmental policy. Robins and Trisoglio (1992) propose ten priorities for an eco-industrial policy: establish a strategic vision, manage structural change, shift to circular industrial ecosystems, design products for needs, build human capacity, ensure corporate accountabilty, use market mechanisms for industrial transformation, guide technological development, foster sustainable livelihoods, and build global partnerships. Corporations in the 21st century will find it essential to be able to innovate and operate competitively while operating in an environmentally responsible manner. Shifts in thinking about the strategic importance of ecoefficiency are already apparent among businesses (Davis and Smith, 1994).
In one recent survey of 200 senior executives in the US, 90% said that environmental considerations were part of their strategic planning process. In another survey of 250 European companies, almost three quarters were found to have specific plans to improve environmental performance. A 1991 report from the Canadian Federation of Independent Business states that 99% of their members are concerned about the state of the natural environment, and that 60% have made, or are about to make, significant changes to their businesses to respond to environmental concerns. The Canadian Standards Association has been working to develop environmental management systems analogous to the ISO 9000 series of Quality Management Standards. The sustainability and competitiveness agendas are addressed by specialized actors in policy networks, lobbies, researchers, government agencies, and some non-governmental not-for-profit institutions. Ultimately, attainment of the twin goals of environmental sustainability and economic competitiveness may well require a much deepened understanding of these complex issues among the public. This is partly because movement toward sustainability and competitiveness requires a multitude of behavioral changes among citizens, and partly because the magnitude of necessary changes requires well-informed voters in democratic political systems. While most of the discussions about sustainability and competitiveness focus on policy and economic incentives, the roles of the public – as consumers, as voters, as civic actors – are important as well. The competitiveness agenda makes an strong set of demands on social values and business culture. If Canada and the United States develop what has been called a “high growth, low employment” economic trajectory, successful social adjustment to technological change will require new social and political skills. The sustainability agenda is analogous. North American consumers say they want to preserve the environment, but “green” marketing does not always elicit the expected responses, and citizens are “wary of the environmental costs they might have to pay as taxpayers, consumers, or workers” (MacEvoy, 1992).
With the exception of markets, mechanisms and instruments of deliberate social choice, especially ones that are feasible under regimes of democratic governance, are a relatively unknown part of the “selection environment” that might lead to ecoefficient industrial innovation. For example, the notion of cleaner production does not rest upon a narrow doctrine of technical efficiency, but on a deeper ambition to gauge the social appropriateness of products (see Jackson 1993b).
Philosophers of industrial metabolism and industrial ecology are attempting to locate principles of extrafirm regulation in efficient systems of transactions among firms, while a current of research attempts to locate the principles of a strong socially determined “selection environment” in processes of social negotiation of technical change.1 Freeman (1992) points out that the issue of eco-efficient industrial production hinges on estimates of the feasibility with which an “accelerated orientation of the science-technology system in the desired direction can be brought about.” As far as common resources are concerned, “sustainability of the system wll depend more on social institutions controlling access than on production technologies” (Lynam and Herdt 1989: 396).
But we have decreasing degrees of freedom as we move from the scientifically conceivable to the technologically feasible, and from there to the economically viable and the socially acceptable (Perez 1983).
In this paper I’ve tried to contextualize the competitiveness and sustainability issues in terms of the North American system of innovation, which is constituted largely of flows of trade, people, technology, and investment across North America, bilateral scientific relations between the major regional power and the two smaller countries, and trade policy rules embodied in a formal agreement. Scientific or technical collaboration at the North American level is quite modest. Undoubtedly the nodes of the regional innovation system are in technologically dynamic metropolitan areas. The contours of the North American innovation system are still indeterminate, depending largely on the innovation strategies and behavior of the corporate world and governments in the North American economic space. For the “smaller” countries of the region, integration into a regional innovation system has particular advantages and disadvantages. Two outstanding questions have to do with business strategy in the new North American economic space, and the scope, aims, and ambition of innovation policy within or pertaining to this space. A number of other issues such as the technological dimensions of regional economic security, the special problems of less-developed regions of North America, the regulation of competition and monopolies at the regional level, and the promotion of ecoefficient industrial innovation remain to be addressed. The ultimate issue is the degree to which ecoefficient industrial production is competitive in the North American or global context. Ardekani, S.A., 1990. “Dematerialization,” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 38(4), 333-347. Ashford, Nicholas A., 1993. “Understanding Technological Responses of Industrial Firms to Environmental Problems: Implications for Government Policy,” pp. 277-307 in Fischer and Schot, eds. Baas, L.W., M. Van der Belt, D. Huisingh, and F. Neumann, 1992. “Cleaner Production: What Some Governments are Doing and What All Governments Can Do to Promote Sustainability,” European Water Pollution Control 2(1), 10-25. Boardman, Robert, ed., 1992. Canadian Environmental Policy: Ecosystems, Politics, and Process. Oxford University Press, Toronto. Bongaerts, Jan C., and Dirk Heinrichs, 1987. “Government Support of Clean Technology Research in West Germany: Some Evidence,” R&D Management 17(1), 39-50. Chadwick, M.J., and J. Nilsson, 1993. “Environmental Quality Objectives: Assimilative Capacity and Critical Load Concepts in Environmental Management,” pp. 29-39 in T. Jackson (ed.), 1993a. Clarke, Tom, and Jean Reavely, 1993. Science and Technology Management Bibliography 1993. Stargate Consultants, Ottawa. Crookell, Harold, 1990. “Subsidiary Strategy in a Free Trade Environment.” Working paper 1990-II, Investment Canada, Ottawa. Daly, D.J., and D.C. MacCharles, 1986. Canadian Manufactured Exports: Constraints and Opportunities. Institute for Research on Public Policy, Montreal. Davis, C.H., 1994a. “Canadian Science Policy and the North American Regional System of Innovation,” Science and Technology Policy (U.K.), forthcoming. Davis, C.H., 1994b. “Innovation and Internationalization: on the New Dynamics of Constructed Advantage in Canada,” paper presented at the International Seminar on Confronting Free Trade: Policies for Technological Development, CIDE, Mexico City, February 1994. Davis, C.H., 1994c. “The Earth Summit and the Promotion of Environmentally Sound Industrial Innovation in Developing Countries,” paper prepared for the ORSTOM/UNESCO Conference on “Science hors la m?tropole,” Paris, September 1994. Davis, C.H., 1993a. “Integraci?n econ?mica de Am?rica del Norte y la pol?tica de innovac?on en Canada,” pp. 105-150 in Consejo Consultivo de Ciencias, Presidencia de la Rep?blica/SECOFI, Seminario Internacional. Ciencia y Tecnolog?a, y Tratado de Libre Comercio. Consejo Consultivo de Ciencias, M?xico. Davis, C.H., and R. Smith, 1994. “Management of Technology and Technological Change in Canada,” in K. Minden and Wong P.K., eds., Developing Technology Managers: Comparative Pacific Rim Strategies, forthcoming. Davis, Charles H., Paul Dufour, and Janet Halliwell, 1993. “La collaboration scientifique et technologique en Am?rique du Nord: un point de vue canadien, ” ?tudes internationales 24(2), 269-296. D’Cruz, Joseph R., and Alan M. Rugman, 1992. New Compacts for Canadian Competitiveness. Kodak Canada, Toronto. Deblock, Christian, and Mich?le Rioux, 1993. “NAFTA: the Trump Card of the United States?,” Studies in Political Economy 41, 7-44. Denison, E., 1985. Trends in American Economic Growth, 1929-1982. The Brookings Institute, Washington. Dethlefsen, V., T. Jackson, and P. Taylor, 1993. “The Precautionary Principle,” pp. 41-62 in T. Jackson (ed.), 1993a. Dielman, Hans, and Sybren de Hoo, 1993. “Towards Tailor-Made Process of Pollution Prevention and Cleaner Production: Results and Implications of the Prisma Project,” pp. 245-276 in Fischer and Schot, eds. Dobson, Andrew, 1990. Green Political Thought. Harper Collins, London. Dosi, Giovani., John Zysman, and Laura D’Andrea Tyson, 1990. “Technology, Trade, and Schumpeterian Efficiencies,” pp. 19-38 in J. de la Mothe and L.-M. Ducharme, eds., Science, Technology and Free Trade. Pinter, London and New York. Doyle, Denzil, 1992. Building a Stronger Environmental Technology Exploitation Capability in Canada. Unpublished report prepared for Environment Canada and Industry, Science and Technology Canada, Ottawa. Dunning, John H., 1993. “Internationalizing Porter’s Diamond,” Management International Review 33(2), 7-15. ECC, 1988. U.S.-Canada Productivity Gap, Scale Economies, and the Gains from Freer Trade. Economic Council of Canada discussion paper no. 357, Ottawa. Eckersely, Robyn, 1992. Environmentalism and Political Theory. Toward and Ecocentric Approach. State University of New York Press, Albany. Eden, Lorraine, 1991. “Multinational Responses to Trade and Technology Changes: Implications for Canada,” pp. 133-171 in McFetridge 1991. Eden, Lorraine, ed., 1994. Multinationales en Am?rique du Nord. University of Calgary Press, Calgary. EPA, 1992. Improving Technology Diffusion for Environmental Protection. Report and Recommendations of the Technology Innovation and Economics Committee. United States Environmental Protection Agency/National Advisory Council for Environmental Policy and Technology, Washington. EPA, 1991. Permitting and Compliance Policy: Barriers to U.S. Environmental Technology Innovation. United States Environmental Protection Agency/National Advisory Council for Environmental Policy and Technology, Washington. Faux, Jeff, and Thea Lee, 1993. “Implications of NAFTA for the United States: Investment, Jobs, and Productivity,” pp. 235-249 in R. Grinspun and M. Cameron, eds. Fishcher, Kurt, and Johan Schot, eds., 1993. Environmental Strategies for Industry. Island Press, Washington, D.C. Fletcher, Joseph F., 1992. Canadian Attitudes Toward Competitiveness and Entrepreneurship. Industry, Science and Technology Canada, Ottawa. Freeman, Christopher, 1992. “A Green Techno-Economic Paradigm for the World Economy,” Chapter 10 in C. Freeman, The Economics of Hope. Essays on Technical Change, Economic Growth and the Environment. Pinter Publishers, London and New York. Gillies, A.M., 1994. Where to Start. An Action Plan for Protecting the Environment and Reducing Canada’s Deficit. International Institute for Sustainable Development, Winnipeg. Globerman, Steven, 1990. “Trade Liberalization and Competitive Behavior: a Note Assessing the Evidence and the Public Policy Implications,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 9(1), 80- 89. Grinspun, Ricardo., and Maxwell Cameron, eds., The Political Economy of North American Free Trade. McGill-Queen’s University Press, Montr?al/Kingston. Hatzichroniglou, Thomas, 1991. “Indicators of Industrial Competitiveness: Results and Limitations,” pp. 177-221 in J. Niosi, ed., Technology and National Competitiveness. Oligopoly, Technological Innovation, and International Competition. McGill- Queen’s University, Press, Montreal and Kingston. Heaton, George, Robert Repetto, and Rodney Sobin, 1992. Backs to the Future: U.S. Government Policy Toward Environmentally Critical Technology. World Resources Institute, Washington. Heaton, George, Robert Repetto, and Rodney Sobin, 1991. Transforming Technology: an Agenda for Environmentally Sustainable Growth in the 21st Century. World Resources Institute, Washington. Herzenberg, Stephen, 1993. “Continental Integration and the Future of the North American Auto Sector,” pp. 303-325 in M. Appel Molot, ed., Driving Continentally. National Policies and the North American Auto Industry. Carleton University Press, Ottawa. Hirschhorn, Joel S., 1992. “Pollution Prevention Implementation in Developing Countries.” Unpublished report prepared for the U.S. Agency for International Development. Hirschhorn, Joel, T. Jackson, and L. Baas, 1993. “Towards Prevention: the Emerging Environmental Management Paradigm,” pp. 125-143 in T. Jackson (ed.), 1993a. Irwin, Alan, and Philip Vergragt, 1989. “Re-thinking the Relationship between Environmental Regulation and Industrial Innovation: the Social Negotiation of Technical Change,” Technology Analysis and Strategic Management 1(1), 57-70. ISTC, 1992. Canada’s Business Culture. Industry, Science and Technology Canada, Ottawa. Jackson, T., (ed.), 1993a. Clean Production Strategies. Developing Preventive Environmental Management in the Industrial Economy. Stockholm Environmental Institute/Lewis Publishers, Boca Raton. Jackson, T., 1993b. “Principles of Clean Production: Developing an Operational Approach to the Prevention Paradigm,” pp. 143-164 in T. Jackson (ed.), 1993a. Jackson, T., 1991. “The Principles of Clean Production: Concepts and Principles for Guiding Technological Choice Towards Sustainable Development,” seminar digest paper, Stockholm Environmental Insititute. Kassiola, Joel Jay, 1990. The Death of Industrial Civilization. The Limits to Economic Growth and the Repoliticization of Advanced Industrial Society. State University of New York Press, Albany. Lipsey, Richard C., 1991. “Rapporteur’s Comments,” pp. 361-388 in McFetridge, 1991. Litvak, Isaiah, 1990. “U.S. Multinationals: Repositioning the Canadian Subsidiary,” Business in the Contemporary World, Autumn, 111-119. Lynam, John K., and Robert W. Herdt, 1989. “Sense and Sustainability: Sustainability as an Objective in International Agricultural Research,” Agricultural Economics 3, 381-398. MacEvoy, Bruce, 1992. Business, the Public, and the Environment. U.S. Environmental Attitudes and Business Strategies. SRI International, Business Intelligence Report no. 812. Martin, Richard, 1992. “Canadian Labour and North American Integration,” pp. 181-188 in S. Randall, H. Konrad, and S. Silverman, eds., North America Without Borders? Integrating Canada, the United States, and Mexico. Univerisity of Calgary Press, Calgary. McFetridge, Donald G., ed., 1993. “The Canadian System of Industrial Innovation,” pp. 299-323 in R. Nelson, ed., 1993. McFetridge, Donald G., ed., 1991. Foreign Investment, Technology and Economic Growth. University of Calgary Press, Calgary. Nelson, Richard R., ed., 1993. National Innovation Systems. A Comparative Analysis. Oxford University Press, N.Y. Niosi, Jorge, 1983. Les multinationales canadiennes. Bor?al Express, Montr?al. Niosi, Jorge, Paolo Saviotti, Bertrand Bellon, and Michael Crow, 1993. “National Systems of Innovation: in Search of a Workable Concept,” Technology in Society 15(2), 207-227. OECD, 1993. Technologies for Cleaner Production and Products: Towards Technological Revolution for Sustainable Development. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris. OECD, 1991. The State of the Environment. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris. OTA, 1994. Industry, Technology, and the Environment. Competitive Challanges and Business Opportunities. Office of Technology Assessment, U.S. Congress, Washington, D.C. Perez, Carlota, 1983. “Structural Change and the Assimilation of New Technologies in the Social and Economic System,” Futures 15(5), 357-375. Pestieau, Caroline, 1993. “Globalization and Restructuring: Aspects of the Canadian Experience,” paper presented at the 1993 Canada-India Economic and Business Policy Linkage Program, New Delhi, January. Philips, Paul, 1991. “New Staples and Mega-Projects: Reaching the Limits to Sustainable Development,” pp. 229-246 in D. Drache and M. Gertler, eds., The New Era of Global Competition: State Policy and Market Power. McGill-Queen’s: Montreal/Kingston. Porter, Michael E., 1991. Canada at the Crossroads. The Reality of a New Competitive Environment. Business Council on National Issues and Ministry of Supply and Services, Ottawa. Porter, Michael E., 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Free Press, New York. Powers, Charles W., 1991. The Role of NGOs in Improving the Employment of Science and Technology in Environmental Management. Working Paper, Carnegie Commission on Science, Technology, and Government, New York. Prosperity, 1992. An Overview of Selected Studies on Canada’s Prosperity and Competitiveness. Prosperity Initiative, Industry, Science and Technology Canada, Ottawa. Rath, Amitav, and Brent Herbert-Copley, 1993. Green Technologies for Development: Transfer, Trade and Cooperation. International Development Research Centre, Ottawa. Rothwell, Roy, and W. Zegvold, 1985. Reindustrialization and Technology. Longman, London. Rugman, Alan M., 1990. Multinationals and Canada-United States Free Trade. University of South Carolina Press, Columbia. Rugman, Alan M., and Joseph D’Cruz, 1993. “The ‘Double Diamond’ Model of International Competitiveness: the Canadian Experience,” Management International Review 33(2), 17-39. SCC, 1992a. Reaching for Tomorrow. Science Council of Canada, Ottawa. SCC, 1992b. The Canadian Non-Ferrous Metals Sector. Sectoral Strategy Series, no. 11. Science Council of Canada, Ottawa. SCC, 1992c. The Canadian Forest Products Sector. Sectoral Strategy Series, no. 9. Science Council of Canada, Ottawa. Shrybman, Steven, 1993. “Trading Away the Environment,” pp. 271-294 in R. Grinspun and M. Cameron, eds. UNIDO/UNEP 1992. “National Cleaner Production Centre Programme. Background Information.” UNIDO and UNEP, Vienna and Paris, December. UNEP/UNIDO 1991. Audit and Reduction Manual for Industrial Emissions and Wastes. Technical Report Series no. 7, United Nations Environment Programme Industry and Environment Office, and United Nations Industrial Development Organization, Paris and Vienna. UNCTAD 1993. Environmental Management in Transnational Corporations. Report of the Benchmark Corporate Environmental Survey. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Programme on Transnational Corporations, New York. United Nations, 1993. World Investment Directory, 1992. V. 3: Developed Countries. Transnational Corporations and Management Division, N.Y. Van den Ven, Andrew, 1993. “A Community Perspective on the Emergence of Innovations,” Journal of Engineering and Technology Management 10: 23-51. Weintraub, Sidney, 1992. “North American Free Trade and the European Situation Compared,” International Migration Review 26: 506-24. Winn, S.F., and N.J. Roome, 1993. “R&D Management Responses to the Environment: Current Theory and Implications to Practice and Research,” R&D Management 23(2), 147-160. Yakowitz, H., and R. Hanmer, 1993. “Policy Options for Clean Production,” pp. 295-322 in T. Jackson, ed., 1993a. Yama*censored*a, Shoichi, 1991. “Japan’s Role as a Regional Technological Integrator in the Pacific Rim,” paper presented at the conference on “The Emerging Technological Trajectory of the Pacific Rim Nations,” Tufts University, Massachusetts. 1 The views expressed here are the author’s own and should not be attributed to the International Development Research Centre. Jos?- Luis Solleiro provided useful comments, for which I am grateful, on an earlier draft. This paper draws on Davis (1993, 1994a and 1994b).
2 In this text I use the terms “science policy,” “science and technology policy,” and “innovation policy” interchangeably. 3 The issue of social sustainability cannot be so simply specified. Insofar as poverty breeds environmental degradation and environmental degradation breeds poverty, linkages between environmental and social sustainability are evident. However, high consumption – as currently practiced, at least – also breeds environmental degradation. In some cases of “traditional” societies with extensive knowledge of the natural environment, social and environmental sustainability are closely linked. 4 In contrast, “invention” refers to the creation of originality or novelty. 5 For example, co-authored U.S.-Canada and U.S.-Mexico scientific publications accounted for about 12% of Canadian scientific output and about 16% of Mexican output in 1990. However, these publications only represent about 2% of American scientific output (Davis, Dufour and Halliwell 1993: 277).
Bilateral Canada-Mexico scientific publications and trilateral Mexico-Canada-U.S. publications are negligible. 6 The issue is not whether unencumbered inward and outward FDI confers important benefits. The issue is whether selective intervention to affect the terms of investments and takeovers in specific cases of strategic importance is warranted (Lipsey 1991).
7 Faux and Lee (1992: 244); see also the discussion in Herzenberg (1993) and Eden (1994).
8 The issues on the competitiveness agenda range from human resources, science, finance, and policy processes, to cultural values and rules of international trade. Forty-five recent reports and studies are described in Prosperity (1992); also useful is SCC (1992a).
9 Porter proposes a four-stage model of national competitiveness development in which capacity to construct advantage grows progressively greater: 1. Factor driven countries draw most of their comparative advantage from basic factors of production. 2. Investment driven countries compete on the basis of standardized products on the basis of foreign technology that has been acquired and adapted. 3. Innovation driven countries appropriate and improve foreign technologies and also create their own. At this stage local clusters of industries become “wider” and “deeper.” 4. In wealth-driven countries substantial outward financial investments lead to a loss of domestic clusters and loss of market share. 10 The clusters are Western forest products, Alberta energy, Prairie farming, metal mining, Ontario automotive, Ontario manufacturing, Toronto financial, Eastern forest products, Montreal aerospatial, and Atlantic seafood. 11 On dematerialization see Ardekani (1990).
12 Similar trends were found in other sectors in Canada. The Canadian pulp and paper industry spent about four times less on R&D than its major American and European competitors. In the forest products industry, which is the largest source of Canada’s trade surplus, relative levels of R&D spending were about half that of major competitors. Only two forest product firms conducted in-house R&D on solid wood products. Industrial R&D staffing fell from six hundred in 1980 to five hundred in 1990 (SCC 1992c).
13 Ashford (1993).
A more comprehensive taxonomy of innovation policy measures which might be applied to environtally sustainable industrial innovation is provided by Rothwell and Zegvold (1985).
14 On proposed environmental tax reform in Canada see Gillies (1994).
15 On attempts to found environmental management regimes on scientific understanding of the behavior of various pollutants in the environment see Chadwick and Nilsson (1993).
16 These are: energy capture (photovoltaics, geothermal, solar thermal electricity, nuclear fission); energy storage and application (batteries, superconductors, hydrogen storage, heat storage, fuel cells); special energy end-uses (transportation, buildings); agricultural biotechnology; improved agricultural techniques; manufacturing monitoring, modeling, and control; catalysis; separations; precision fabricatyion; materials design and processing; information, communications, and computing; and contraception. 17 See for example Irwin and Vergragt (1989).
Radical social innovation for environmental sustainability is especially problematic. Massive changes in lifestyles and consumption would require social engineering, coercive policies, or extremely rapid social learning on an unprecedented scale. On the efforts (largely in Northern countries) to define frameworks for “green” political action see Eckersley (1992) and Dobson (1990).
On the question of the politics of the social transition to sustainability see, for example, Kassiola (1990), especially chapter 9, “Social Transformation into a Transindustrial Community.”